Why do political revolutions occur
This simple model is able to reproduce several patterns of rebellion consistent with major historical revolutions: a pre-revolutionary period characterised by spontaneous riots, motivated mainly by poor economic conditions and social inequality, gives way to an actual revolutionary rebellion, in which organised elements mobilise popular masses against the central government. Moreover, the model provides an explanation for the multiplicity of outcomes that can arise from an uprising: a completely successful revolution leading to the overthrow of the central authority; a failed rebellion followed by a return to the status quo; an intermediate case where the uprising is unable to change the political system, but is sufficiently strong to destabilise the country and drive it towards anarchy.
The heterogeneity of scenarios predicted by the model is not highlighted in existing literature, and its importance can be understood by considering the recent experience of the Arab Spring involving several rebellions that arose in an apparently similar way, but resulted in completely different political outcomes: e.
For decades, the most popular conceptualisations of revolution were the Marxian theory and the relative deprivation theory. The former emphasises the role of changes in production methods in generating discontent and rebellion; the latter focuses on the gap between economic expectations and realised economic performances to explain the sense of frustration and, consequently, riot participation.
Both theories establish an automatic link between the structural conditions that generate grievance in society and the likelihood of revolutionary episodes. Moreover, in both theories participation in rebellion is motivated by a collective good argument, such as the desire to change the oppressive social order. Two of the most influential scholars in this stream of literature are Skocpol [ 1 ] with regard to the Marxian theory and Davies [ 2 ] concerning the relative deprivation theory.
For a complete review of the political science literature about revolutions, see Goldstone [ 3 ]. In contrast, Tullock [ 4 ] develops an economic approach to explain participation in revolutions: since the benefit of an extra unit of public good is small relative to the cost of obtaining it by participating in a rebellion, individuals decide whether or not to participate based on their private gains or losses.
Moreover, Kuran [ 6 — 8 ] criticises the idea of an automatic relationship between social grievance and revolution, arguing that most historical revolutions were unanticipated. He provides an explanation based on the observation that people who dislike their government tend to conceal their political preferences as long as the opposition seems weak. For this reason, regimes that appear to be absolutely stable may experience a sudden loss of support in the event of a minor increase in the size of the opposition, even if triggered by insignificant events.
The economic and political science literature have endeavoured to solve the collective action problems inherent in revolutions.
For example, in criticism of Tullock, Lichbach [ 9 — 11 ] identifies a number of solutions based on sanctioning and group identification methods. These solutions include the possibility of imposing community obligations, establishing institutional mechanisms, arranging contracts and using authority. For an example of an institutional kind of solution in the context of 18th century merchant sailors, see Leeson [ 12 ]. This is because citizens in such political systems have a greater incentive to conceal their true political opinions in order to avoid economic or legal sanctions being imposed by the central authority.
Makowsky and Rubin [ 14 ] extend the previous work by developing an agent-based model to study how social network technology favours preference revelation in centralised societies.
An alternative view is represented by the paper of Gard-Murray and Bar-Yam [ 17 ], who argue that democracies are more systemically complex than autocracies and, since violent revolutions are likely to disrupt existing evolved complexity, dictatorships have higher chances of emerging after uprisings. According to Granovetter, individuals face many situations with multiple alternatives, and the costs and benefits associated with these alternatives depend on how many other individuals have chosen the various options in the past.
For this reason, each individual has a personal threshold, and decides to join collective action, such as a riot or a strike, if the number of people participating at that time exceeds this threshold. Following this idea, Epstein develops an agent-based model of civil violence involving two types of player, agents and cops, interacting in a bidimensional torus space. In this model the agents decide to rebel against the government if their level of grievance corrected by the risk of being arrested by the cops exceeds their activation threshold.
One of the main findings of this model is that intermittent outbursts of violence occur, distributed irregularly over time and space. Another study that explores the temporal and spatial diffusion of civil unrest is that produced by Braha [ 20 ]. In particular, his paper demonstrates that the distribution of real episodes of civil violence can be replicated using a spatially extended dynamical model that incorporates the effects of social and communication networks.
The rest of the paper is organised as follows: the next section describes the model; in the Results section, the three outcomes generated by the model are presented and their dependence on the model parameters is analysed using graphical and statistical tools; the final section discusses the results and their relevance for analysing contemporary revolutions.
In the agent-based computational model presented in this paper, there are three types of agent that interact in a bidimensional torus space: citizens, policemen and revolutionaries. Citizens are members of a population subjugated to a central authority who decide whether or not to rebel against the government based on their degree of economic and political grievance.
Revolutionaries are members of an organised opposition group that seeks to overthrow the central government by an armed uprising.
Policemen are the forces loyal to the central authority that have been tasked to suppress any kind of revolt by arresting rebellious citizens and killing revolutionaries.
In this section, the features of each agent are described in detail, beginning with the citizen specification. This expression is similar to the definition of grievance employed by Kim and Hanneman [ 21 ].
The main difference with respect to their specification is that the two authors use a local measure of inequality, i. On the other hand, the cost of participating in a rebellion is defined as the product of the estimated probability of being arrested A i and the opportunity cost of joining a revolt J : 4 In fact, each citizen estimates the probability of being arrested before actively joining a rebellion.
The one in the previous formula makes explicit that, before participating in a riot, a citizen will count himself as an active agent: thus the ratio is always well defined. If an active citizen is arrested by a policeman, he remains in jail for a number of periods drawn from a uniform distribution on the 0, j max interval.
For this reason, the opportunity cost of rebelling is defined as a function of the maximum number of periods in jail j max , multiplied by income loss whilst in jail: 6 Since the inner argument of the logistic transformation is positive, given that income assumes only positive values, the logistic function is rescaled in order to define a cost function J on the 0, 1 interval. Expression 6 is also consistent with the literature on political violence, which finds a negative relationship between income and participation in civil violence phenomena.
For example, Collier and Hoeffler [ 23 , 24 ] and Fearon and Laitin [ 25 ], using cross-country regressions, find that economic growth and per capita income correlate negatively with the risk of civil conflict. Moreover, Miguel, Satyanath and Sergenti [ 26 ] identify a causal negative effect between positive income shocks and civil war incidence in Sub-Saharan African countries employing an instrumental variable approach. Citizens particularly become active, meaning that they decide to rebel against the government, if the difference between their social grievance and the expected opportunity cost of joining a riot exceeds a fixed threshold; otherwise, they will keep quiet.
Revolutionaries are members of an organised group that attempts to overthrow the government by an armed conflict. This kind of agent can be interpreted as a proper revolutionary group or as defected elements from the military that decide to side with the population in revolt. Defections from the military are also very common in all revolutions: a typical example is the pro-Khomeini members of the Iranian Air Force who fought against the loyal Immortal Guards during the uprisings.
Rule R: if be active and kill a randomly selected policeman inside vision radius v with a probability equal to r ; otherwise, remain hidden. Here R , C and P are the total number of revolutionaries, the total number of active citizens and the total number of policemen, respectively. Rule R means that revolutionaries decide to become active when the ratio of rebel forces to policemen loyal to the government exceeds a given threshold n.
In this respect, revolutionaries are different from citizens: citizens choose how to behave according to local information available within their vision radius. In contrast, revolutionaries act on the basis of global information and decide when to start a revolution by employing a threshold-based rule involving the total number of active citizens in the population. In fact, it is assumed that the revolutionary organisation is spread across the country, enabling it to obtain an estimate of the total number of active agents in the population.
When a revolutionary is active, he kills a randomly selected policeman in his vision radius with a probability equal to r. Otherwise, when the ratio is less than the fixed threshold, all revolutionaries will remain hidden among quiet citizens and policemen will be unable to identify them.
As far as policemen are concerned, they simply inspect the lattice positions inside their vision radius and randomly choose an active citizen or active revolutionary: if the randomly selected agent is a citizen, the policeman will arrest him, or will kill him if he is an active revolutionary with a probability equal to p.
Rule P: randomly select an agent from the active citizens and active revolutionaries within vision radius v. If the randomly selected agent is a citizen, arrest him; if he is a revolutionary, kill him with a probability equal to p.
The same vision radius v is assumed for citizens, revolutionaries and policemen. Furthermore, parameters r and p can also be interpreted in terms of weapon precision or, more broadly, in terms of effectiveness in the military capacity of the conflicting parties. Once killed, revolutionaries and policemen are simply removed from the bidimensional space.
Finally, citizens who are not in jail, revolutionaries and policemen who are not killed can move in the lattice space to a random site without agents or in which there are only jailed citizens following this simple rule:. Rule M: within vision radius v , randomly move to an empty site or to a site in which there are only jailed citizens.
Table 1 presents the parameter values that are kept constant in all model simulations: the values assigned to the lognormal parameters a , b and the cost function parameter w 2 are selected in order to obtain a widespread distribution of hardship and opportunity costs on the 0, 1 interval, avoiding concentration at the extremes of that interval; the other values are assigned according to those selected by Epstein [ 19 ].
The next section of the paper investigates the effects of the new parameters introduced by the present model, i. At the beginning of each model simulation, the random values y i are drawn from the lognormal distribution and the different agents are randomly situated on the sites of the lattice.
Then, an agent is selected at random. Under rule M, he moves to a random position within his vision, where he acts according to rule C if he is a citizen, rule R if he is a revolutionary or rule P if he is a policeman. This procedure is replicated until a given time or a specific condition e.
The model was written using NetLogo Wilensky [ 27 ] , whereas the statistical analysis was performed using R R Core Team [ 28 ] : details of implementation and the code are in the S1 Code file, in the supplementary material.
Three distinct outcomes can be identified by simulating this simple model: a successful revolution in which all policemen are killed by revolutionaries, leading to an overthrow of the central government; a failed revolution followed by a state of anarchy due to the large number of policemen killed; a completely failed revolution with only a few policemen killed, signifying a return to the status quo after the uprising.
All three simulations start with a period of instability characterised by minor revolts where the poorest component of the population, made up of citizens with the greatest degree of grievance and the lowest opportunity cost, decides to rebel. However, these riots are too small, meaning that they do not degenerate into a revolution. This politically unstable pre-revolutionary period is a common feature of many historical revolutions: e.
The web site also provides information and pricing for all printed volumes, online publications, and reprint collections. Annual Review of Sociology. Cite this Item. Read and download Log in through your school or library.
Alternate access options. Get Started Already have an account? How does it work? Select the purchase option. Check out using a credit card or bank account with PayPal. He also says his ideas can be applied to current situations such as the rise of the Tea Party movement in the United States, which he notes is more a case of resistance or rebellion than revolution.
A Future Full of Promise. Southwestern Celebrates the Inauguration of our 16th President. The Making of the Mark. Southwestern University Announces Dr. Ruth J. Simmons as Shilling Lecture Speaker. Countering Terrorism through Research. Rare Moments. Southwestern University a Best Value among U. Inauguration and Homecoming Weekend Highlights. Southwestern alumnus nominated for Grammy Award. Close Search Southwestern… Go.
0コメント